Andrew Brown, Director of Policy Influence and Engagement offers some reflections on the 2014 annual conference of the European
Society of Prevention Research
The European Society for
Prevention Research (EUSPR) brings together researchers and practitioners
from across Europe across a range of topics including substance use, obesity,
criminal justice and mental health. Last
week 180 members and delegates from across the continent attended the society’s
annual conference to listen and debate the economics of prevention.
At the heart of this year's conference, at
least for me, has been a question of how prevention science works to influence
policy.
A number of keynote speakers raised the question of why
strongly evidenced interventions remain unused while ineffective prevention
continues to have the confidence of policy makers. The answers seemed to focus
around three things:
·
Public support for the least evidenced and
hostility to interventions that may challenge their existing behaviours,
·
Other actors working actively against the
introduction of those policies, and
·
The weakness of prevention science in developing
values messages that work with the grain of evidence.
But I also heard researchers and practitioners banding
together to learn from approaches that were having traction. Whether that was
the Social Research Unit in the UK
working closely with the Washington State
Institute for Public Policy (WISPP) to build robust benefit & cost models
for particular interventions, or by developing international standards for
prevention under the wing of either the UN
or EMCDDA.
I also heard presentations about designing systems that worked from the bottom
up, including an impressive attempt to professionalise the workforce in school
prevention coming out of the Czech Republic and a group that are in the process
of designing a Universal
Prevention Curriculum.
But, the challenge of change is significant, and we were
warned that over claiming for the ability of prevention to make a difference could
add to any existing scepticism. Franco Sassi from the OECD argued that while prevention is
likely to be cost effective it was unlikely to lead to large cashable savings
in health systems. He also reminded us that early death could be less expensive
than the costs associated with long life.
I felt his take home message was to recognise that policy
makers are having to prioritise increasingly limited resources and that cost
effectiveness information could be an important tool to help them choose where
that investment would achieve the most change.
Another useful perspective on the importance of the economic
argument came from Stephanie Lee from WSIPP. She told us how by working up
robust cost benefit analysis of interventions - always taking a conservative
estimate of effect and benefit - they have been able to persuade policy makers
to put aside a proportion of their budget to commission evidence based
interventions.
She also said that the analysis the institute has done
led to a reduction in the use of incarceration for non-violent drug offences.
Stephanie argued that being able to show where cost lie
and benefits will accrue alongside an ability to predict whether the money
spent on the intervention would be returned had been a powerful tool in their
discussions with politicians.
Two later speakers, Professor Peter Anderson
and Professor
Theresa Marteau turned our attention towards additional influences on
policy; other interests (particularly economic interests) and public acceptance
of interventions. Both offered a useful reminder of the tightrope that
politicians and other policy makers walk in making their decisions, and that
the strength of evidence is only one consideration.
Professor Anderson used a case study of the influence of
part of the alcohol industry on UK government policy in relation to minimum
unit pricing (MUP). Drawing extensively
on investigative
journalism he showed how industry representatives were able to engage
senior Ministers in ways that weren't open to public health interests. He
argued that across a number of public health issues the relationship between
industry and governments across Europe was working against the interest of
health and that the public health field should avoid being co-opted in attempts
to co-produce health policy.
Professor Marteau took us through some of her research
about how the public respond to population level interventions. She said that
where the public didn't take part in the behaviour under discussion (drinking,
smoking, eating fast food) they were pretty happy for governments to do
whatever they like: raise taxes, increase the size of warnings, reduce
availability, etc. But as soon as it was
something that effected them, attitudes were much less amenable to hard
interventions.
Professor Marteau said that her focus group work
suggested the public are reluctant for policy makers to employ policies like
MUP for a number of reasons: they express scepticism about price as a mechanism
to change behaviour ("people will just spend more of what they've got on
the product"), government intentions are always bad ("rapacious"
"they just want more of my money"), & low trust of government
messaging on evidence ("they would say that").
Professor Marteau suggested that should policy makers
want to make the case for price led interventions they may need to think about
hypothecation so that consumers and voters see clearly where tax take ends up
being spent.
Another suggestion on how to increase policy makers’
confidence in evidence based interventions was made by Professor
Fabrizo Faggiano who pointed out that in the pharmaceutical world 5-10,000 compounds
are investigated for each medicine reaching the market. He said we should follow a similar procedure
and develop what he called a transparent,
and evidence-based approval process for prevention interventions. This ambitious idea would see only those
interventions that show convincing results being approved for widespread
delivery to its target population.
My sense at the end of the conference was that while our
keynote speakers were slightly pessimistic about the ability to move policy
makers, other attendees went away with practical strategies they could adapt
from the presentations in parallel sessions and through conversations in the
informal networking that would be useful in the real world.
I left knowing that having a clear-eyed view of the
economics of prevention, taking a cautious view of the benefits and realistic
sense of the costs of implementation, has started to change how policy makers
commission prevention services, and is more likely to lead to the widest
roll-out of interventions, even if it takes time to get there.
No comments:
Post a Comment